| by Michael Hudson
A longer version of this article in
German was published in the Frankfurter Algemeine Zeitung on December 5, 2011
(October 18, 2012, Washington DC,
Sri Lanka Guardian) Book V of Aristotle’s Politics describes the eternal
transition of oligarchies making themselves into hereditary aristocracies –
which end up being overthrown by tyrants or develop internal rivalries as some
families decide to “take the multitude into their camp” and usher in democracy,
within which an oligarchy emerges once again, followed by aristocracy,
democracy, and so on throughout history.
Debt has been the main dynamic
driving these shifts – always with new twists and turns. It polarizes wealth to
create a creditor class, whose oligarchic rule is ended as new leaders
(“tyrants” to Aristotle) win popular support by cancelling the debts and
redistributing property or taking its usufruct for the state.
Since the Renaissance, however,
bankers have shifted their political support to democracies. This did not
reflect egalitarian or liberal political convictions as such, but rather a
desire for better security for their loans. As James Steuart explained in 1767,
royal borrowings remained private affairs rather than truly public debts. For a
sovereign’s debts to become binding upon the entire nation, elected
representatives had to enact the taxes to pay their interest charges.
By giving taxpayers this voice in
government, the Dutch and British democracies provided creditors with much
safer claims for payment than did kings and princes whose debts died with them.
But the recent debt protests from Iceland to Greece and Spain suggest that
creditors are shifting their support away from democracies. They are demanding
fiscal austerity and even privatization sell-offs.
This is turning international
finance into a new mode of warfare. Its objective is the same as military
conquest in times past: to appropriate land and mineral resources, communal
infrastructure and extract tribute. In response, democracies are demanding
referendums over whether to pay creditors by selling off the public domain and
raising taxes to impose unemployment, falling wages and economic depression.
The alternative is to write down debts or even annul them, and to re-assert
regulatory control over the financial sector.
Near Eastern Rulers Proclaimed Clean
Slates to Preserve Economic Balance
Charging interest on advances of
goods or money was not originally intended to polarize economies. First
administered early in the third millennium BC as a contractual arrangement by
Sumer’s temples and palaces with merchants and entrepreneurs who typically
worked in the royal bureaucracy, interest at 20% (doubling the principal in
five years) was supposed to approximate a fair share of the returns from
long-distance trade or leasing land and other public assets such as workshops,
boats and ale houses.
As the practice was privatized by
royal collectors of user fees and rents, “divine kingship” protected agrarian
debtors. Hammurabi’s laws (c. 1750 BC) cancelled their debts in times of flood
or drought. All the rulers of his Babylonian dynasty began their first full
year on the throne by cancelling agrarian debts so as to clear out payment
arrears by proclaiming a clean slate. Bondservants, land or crop rights and
other pledges were returned to the debtors to “restore order” in an idealized
“original” condition of balance. This practice survived in the Jubilee Year of
Mosaic Law in Leviticus 25.
The logic was clear enough. Ancient
societies needed to field armies to defend their land, and this required
liberating indebted citizens from bondage. Hammurabi’s laws protected
charioteers and other fighters from being reduced to debt bondage, and blocked
creditors from taking the crops of tenants on royal and other public lands and
on communal land that owed manpower and military service to the palace.
In Egypt, the pharaoh Bakenranef (c.
720-715 BC, “Bocchoris” in Greek) proclaimed a debt amnesty and abolished
debt-servitude when faced with a military threat from Ethiopia. According to
Diodorus of Sicily (I, 79, writing in 40-30 BC), he ruled that if a debtor
contested the claim, the debt was nullified if the creditor could not back up
his claim by producing a written contract. (It seems that creditors always have
been prone to exaggerate the balances due.) The pharaoh reasoned that “the
bodies of citizens should belong to the state, to the end that it might avail
itself of the services which its citizens owed it, in times of both war and
peace. For he felt that it would be absurd for a soldier … to be haled to
prison by his creditor for an unpaid loan, and that the greed of private
citizens should in this way endanger the safety of all.”
The fact that the main Near Eastern
creditors were the palace, temples and their collectors made it politically
easy to cancel the debts. It always is easy to annul debts owed to oneself.
Even Roman emperors burned the tax records to prevent a crisis. But it was much
harder to cancel debts owed to private creditors as the practice of charging
interest spread westward to Mediterranean chiefdoms after about 750 BC. Instead
of enabling families to bridge gaps between income and outgo, debt became the
major lever of land expropriation, polarizing communities between creditor
oligarchies and indebted clients. In Judah, the prophet Isaiah (5:8-9) decried
foreclosing creditors who “add house to house and join field to field till no
space is left and you live alone in the land.”
Creditor power and stable growth
rarely have gone together. Most personal debts in this classical period were
the product of small amounts of money lent to individuals living on the edge of
subsistence and who could not make ends meet. Forfeiture of land and assets –
and personal liberty – forced debtors into bondage that became irreversible. By
the 7th century BC, “tyrants” (popular leaders) emerged to overthrow the
aristocracies in Corinth and other wealthy Greek cities, gaining support by
cancelling the debts. In a less tyrannical manner, Solon founded the Athenian
democracy in 594 BC by banning debt bondage.
But oligarchies re-emerged and
called in Rome when Sparta’s kings Agis, Cleomenes and their successor Nabis
sought to cancel debts late in the third century BC. They were killed and their
supporters driven out. It has been a political constant of history since
antiquity that creditor interests opposed both popular democracy and royal
power able to limit the financial conquest of society and an almost autonomous
dynamic turning the economic surplus into interest-bearing debt claims for
payment.
When the Gracchi brothers and their
followers tried to reform the credit laws in 133 BC, the dominant Senatorial
class acted with violence, killing them and inaugurating a century of Social
War, resolved by the ascension of Augustus as emperor in 29 BC.
Rome’s Creditor Oligarchy Wins the
Social War, Enserfs the Population and Brings on a Dark Age
Matters were more bloody abroad.
Aristotle did not mention empire building as part of his political schema, but
foreign conquest always has been a major factor in imposing debts, and war
debts have been the major cause of public debt in modern times. Antiquity’s
harshest debt levy was by Rome, whose creditors spread out to plague Asia
Minor, its most prosperous province. The rule of law all but disappeared when
publican creditors arrived. Mithridates of Pontus led three popular revolts,
and local populations in Ephesus and other cities rose up and killed a reported
80,000 Romans in 88 BC. The Roman army retaliated, and Sulla imposed war
tribute of 20,000 talents in 84 BC. Charges for back interest multiplied this
sum six-fold by 70 BC.
Among Rome’s leading historians,
Livy, Plutarch and Diodorus blamed the fall of the Republic on creditor
intransigence in waging the century-long Social War marked by political murder
from 133 to 29 BC. Populist leaders sought to gain a following by advocating
debt cancellations (e.g., the Catiline conspiracy in 63-62 BC). They were
killed. By the second century AD about a quarter of the population was reduced
to bondage. By the fifth century Rome’s economy collapsed, stripped of money.
Subsistence life reverted to the countryside as a Dark Age descended.
Creditors Find a Legalistic Reason
to Support Parliamentary Democracy
When banking recovered after the
Crusades looted Byzantium and infused silver and gold to review Western
European commerce, Christian opposition to charging interest was overcome by
the combination of prestigious lenders (the Knights Templars and Hospitallers
providing credit during the Crusades) and their major clients – kings, at first
to pay the Church and increasingly to wage war. But royal debts went bad when
kings died. The Bardi and Peruzzi went bankrupt in 1345 when Edward III
repudiated his war debts. Banking families lost more on loans to the Habsburg
and Bourbon despots on the thrones of Spain, Austria and France.
Matters changed with the Dutch
democracy, seeking to win and secure its liberty from Habsburg Spain. The fact
that their parliament was to contract permanent public debts on behalf of the
state enabled the Low Countries to raise loans to employ mercenaries in an
epoch when money and credit were the sinews of war. Access to credit “was
accordingly their most powerful weapon in the struggle for their freedom,”
notes Ehrenberg: “Anyone who gave credit to a prince knew that the repayment of
the debt depended only on his debtor’s capacity and will to pay. The case was
very different for the cities, which had power as overlords, but were also
corporations, associations of individuals held in common bond. According to the
generally accepted law each individual burgher was liable for the debts of the
city both with his person and his property.”
The financial achievement of
parliamentary government was thus to establish debts that were not merely the
personal obligations of princes, but were truly public and binding regardless
of who occupied the throne. This is why the first two democratic nations, the
Netherlands and Britain after its 1688 revolution, developed the most active
capital markets and proceeded to become leading military powers. What is ironic
is that it was the need for war financing that promoted democracy, forming a
symbiotic trinity between war making, credit and parliamentary democracy in an
epoch when money was still the sinews of war.
At this time “the legal position of
the King qua borrower was obscure, and it was still doubtful whether his
creditors had any remedy against him in case of default.” The more despotic
Spain, Austria and France became, the greater the difficulty they found in
financing their military adventures. By the end of the eighteenth century
Austria was left “without credit, and consequently without much debt” the least
credit-worthy and worst armed country in Europe (as Steuart 1767:373 noted),
fully dependent on British subsidies and loan guarantees by the time of the
Napoleonic Wars.
Finance Accommodates Itself to
Democracy, but Then Pushes for Oligarchy
While the nineteenth century’s
democratic reforms reduced the power of landed aristocracies to control
parliaments, bankers moved flexibly to achieve a symbiotic relationship with
nearly every form of government. In France, followers of Saint-Simon promoted
the idea of banks acting like mutual funds, extending credit against equity
shares in profit. The German state made an alliance with large banking and
heavy industry. Marx wrote optimistically about how socialism would make
finance productive rather than parasitic. In the United States, regulation of
public utilities went hand in hand with guaranteed returns. In China,
Sun-Yat-Sen wrote in 1922: “I intend to make all the national industries of
China into a Great Trust owned by the Chinese people, and financed with
international capital for mutual benefit.”
World War I saw the United States
replace Britain as the major creditor nation, and by the end of World War II it
had cornered some 80 percent of the world’s monetary gold. Its diplomats shaped
the IMF and World Bank along creditor-oriented lines that financed trade
dependency, mainly on the United States. Loans to finance trade and payments
deficits were subject to “conditionalities” that shifted economic planning to
client oligarchies and military dictatorships. The democratic response to
resulting austerity plans squeezing out debt service was unable to go much
beyond “IMF riots,” until Argentina rejected its foreign debt.
A similar creditor-oriented
austerity is now being imposed on Europe by the European Central Bank (ECB) and
EU bureaucracy. Ostensibly social democratic governments have been directed to
save the banks rather than reviving economic growth and employment. Losses on
bad bank loans and speculations are taken onto the public balance sheet while
scaling back public spending and even selling off infrastructure. The response
of taxpayers stuck with the resulting debt has been to mount popular protests
starting in Iceland and Latvia in January 2009, and more widespread
demonstrations in Greece and Spain this autumn to protest their governments’
refusal to hold referendums on these fateful bailouts of foreign bondholders.
Shifting Planning Away From Elected
Public Representatives To Bankers
Every economy is planned. This
traditionally has been the function of government. Relinquishing this role
under the slogan of “free markets” leaves it in the hands of banks. Yet the
planning privilege of credit creation and allocation turns out to be even more
centralized than that of elected public officials. And to make matters worse,
the financial time frame is short-term hit-and-run, ending up as asset
stripping. By seeking their own gains, the banks tend to destroy the economy.
The surplus ends up being consumed by interest and other financial charges,
leaving no revenue for new capital investment or basic social spending.
This is why relinquishing policy
control to a creditor class rarely has gone together with economic growth and
rising living standards. The tendency for debts to grow faster than the
population’s ability to pay has been a basic constant throughout all recorded
history. Debts mount up exponentially, absorbing the surplus and reducing much
of the population to the equivalent of debt peonage. To restore economic
balance, antiquity’s cry for debt cancellation sought what the Bronze Age Near
East achieved by royal fiat: to cancel the overgrowth of debts.
In more modern times, democracies
have urged a strong state to tax rentier income and wealth, and when called
for, to write down debts. This is done most readily when the state itself
creates money and credit. It is done least easily when banks translate their
gains into political power. When banks are permitted to be self-regulating and
given veto power over government regulators, the economy is distorted to permit
creditors to indulge in the speculative gambles and outright fraud that have
marked the past decade. The fall of the Roman Empire demonstrates what happens
when creditor demands are unchecked. Under these conditions the alternative to
government planning and regulation of the financial sector becomes a road to
debt peonage.
Finance vs. Government; Oligarchy
vs. Democracy
Democracy involves subordinating
financial dynamics to serve economic balance and growth – and taxing rentier
income or keeping basic monopolies in the public domain. Untaxing or
privatizing property income “frees” it to be pledged to the banks, to be
capitalized into larger loans. Financed by debt leveraging, asset-price
inflation increases rentier wealth while indebting the economy at large. The
economy shrinks, falling into negative equity.
The financial sector has gained
sufficient influence to use such emergencies as an opportunity to convince
governments that that the economy will collapse they it do not “save the
banks.” In practice this means consolidating their control over policy, which
they use in ways that further polarize economies. The basic model is what
occurred in ancient Rome, moving from democracy to oligarchy. In fact, giving
priority to bankers and leaving economic planning to be dictated by the EU, ECB
and IMF threatens to strip the nation-state of the power to coin or print money
and levy taxes.
The resulting conflict is pitting
financial interests against national self-determination. The idea of an
independent central bank being “the hallmark of democracy” is a euphemism for
relinquishing the most important policy decision – the ability to create money
and credit – to the financial sector. Rather than leaving the policy choice to
popular referendums, the rescue of banks organized by the EU and ECB now
represents the largest category of rising national debt. The private bank debts
taken onto government balance sheets in Ireland and Greece have been turned
into taxpayer obligations. The same is true for America’s $13 trillion added
since September 2008 (including $5.3 trillion in Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac bad
mortgages taken onto the government’s balance sheet, and $2 trillion of Federal
Reserve “cash-for-trash” swaps).
This is being dictated by financial
proxies euphemized as technocrats. Designated by creditor lobbyists, their role
is to calculate just how much unemployment and depression is needed to squeeze
out a surplus to pay creditors for debts now on the books. What makes this
calculation self-defeating is the fact that economic shrinkage – debt deflation
– makes the debt burden even more unpayable.
Neither banks nor public authorities
(or mainstream academics, for that matter) calculated the economy’s realistic
ability to pay – that is, to pay without shrinking the economy. Through their
media and think tanks, they have convinced populations that the way to get rich
most rapidly is to borrow money to buy real estate, stocks and bonds rising in
price – being inflated by bank credit – and to reverse the past century’s progressive
taxation of wealth.
To put matters bluntly, the result
has been junk economics. Its aim is to disable public checks and balances,
shifting planning power into the hands of high finance on the claim that this
is more efficient than public regulation. Government planning and taxation is
accused of being “the road to serfdom,” as if “free markets” controlled by
bankers given leeway to act recklessly is not planned by special interests in
ways that are oligarchic, not democratic. Governments are told to pay bailout
debts taken on not to defend countries in military warfare as in times past,
but to benefit the wealthiest layer of the population by shifting its losses
onto taxpayers.
The failure to take the wishes of
voters into consideration leaves the resulting national debts on shaky ground
politically and even legally. Debts imposed by fiat, by governments or foreign
financial agencies in the face of strong popular opposition may be as tenuous
as those of the Habsburgs and other despots in past epochs. Lacking popular
validation, they may die with the regime that contracted them. New governments
may act democratically to subordinate the banking and financial sector to serve
the economy, not the other way around.
At the very least, they may seek to pay
by re-introducing progressive taxation of wealth and income, shifting the
fiscal burden onto rentier wealth and property. Re-regulation of banking and
providing a public option for credit and banking services would renew the
social democratic program that seemed well underway a century ago.
Iceland and Argentina are most
recent examples, but one may look back to the moratorium on Inter-Ally arms
debts and German reparations in 1931.A basic mathematical as well as political
principle is at work: Debts that can’t be paid, won’t be.
Michael Hudson, a research professor
of Economics at University of Missouri, Kansas City and a research associate at
the Levy Economics Institute of Bard College
Notes:
1.James Steuart, Principles of
Political Oeconomy (1767), p. 353.
2. Richard Ehrenberg, Capital and Finance in the Age of the Renaissance (1928):44f., 33.
3. Charles Wilson, England’s Apprenticeship: 1603-1763 (London: 1965):89.
4. Sun Yat-Sen, The International Development of China (1922):231ff.
2. Richard Ehrenberg, Capital and Finance in the Age of the Renaissance (1928):44f., 33.
3. Charles Wilson, England’s Apprenticeship: 1603-1763 (London: 1965):89.
4. Sun Yat-Sen, The International Development of China (1922):231ff.